Game Theory Analysis of a Script Deviation
This scenario, where six actors perform six scenes and one deviates from the script in the final scene, can be rigorously analyzed using game theory. The structure is that of a strategic interaction with multiple decision points.
Game-Theoretic Framework
- Players: The 6 actors.
- Stages/Sequential Moves: The 6 scenes. Each scene represents a distinct stage in the game where actors make choices (follow the script or deviate).
- Strategies: Each actor's plan of action for every possible situation in every scene. The "script" is the predefined, coordinated strategy profile.
- Deviation: A unilateral change in strategy by one player in the final stage.
- Payoffs: The outcome (e.g., critical reception, personal satisfaction, future casting) for each actor, which depends on the sequence of actions taken by all players. The result is "notated similarly to the original script," implying a clear comparison of outcomes.
Primary Game Type: Finite Repeated Game
This is most accurately modeled as a finite sequential game with observed actions and complete information. It is "repeated" because the same group of players interact over multiple discrete rounds (scenes), and "finite" because the number of rounds (6) is known to all players from the outset.
The key feature of such games is that players can observe the actions taken in previous stages before making their next decision, allowing for strategies based on reciprocity or punishment.
Solution Concept: Backward Induction & SPNE
The logical way to analyze this game is through backward induction, working from the final stage backwards to find the optimal strategy.
- Final Scene (Scene 6): Since there is no future scene, there is no possibility of punishment for deviating. The actor must choose the action that maximizes their immediate payoff. If deviating offers a higher personal payoff than following the script—regardless of what others do—then rational play dictates a Nash Equilibrium in this final subgame where deviation is the best response.
- Earlier Scenes (Scenes 1-5): Knowing that defection in the final scene is inevitable (because it is a Nash Equilibrium), the threat of "punishment" in future rounds for current defection loses all credibility. Applying backward induction, cooperation unravels from the back. The only Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium (SPNE)—where strategies form a Nash Equilibrium in every subgame—is for all actors to deviate from the start.
The Paradox & The Real-World Twist
This creates a paradox: logic dictates always deviating, yet we often observe cooperation in the real world (actors follow the script). This mirrors the famous Finitely Repeated Prisoner's Dilemma and the Chainstore Paradox.
The fact that the actors did cooperate until the last scene suggests that the real-world game may have elements not captured by the simple model, such as:
- Incomplete Information: Perhaps actors are uncertain about each other's rationality or payoffs (e.g., a "crazy" type who would punish deviators even in the last round).
- Reputation & Norms: The payoff for maintaining a reputation as a cooperative team player for future plays (outside this specific 6-scene game) may outweigh the short-term gain from deviating in scene 6.
- Contractual Obligations: External enforcement (e.g., fines for breaking contract) changes the payoff structure, making "Follow the Script" the dominant strategy in all rounds.
Conclusion
The play is best analyzed as a Finitely Repeated Game. The deviation in the last scene is a predictable outcome of rational play under the solution concept of Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium (SPNE), found through backward induction. The notation of the result would show the payoff consequences of this final-stage deviation, highlighting the difference between the planned (scripted) equilibrium and the actual equilibrium reached.
No comments:
Post a Comment